10/11/2011
botwinick, oct 11th
new left falsely
understood lack of labour organizing as failure of Marxism; in fact,
it's consistent with a more clearly reconstructed version of Marxism,
and an appreciation of the obstacles to organizing.
these are internal
constraints on the organization of labour.
today we'll discuss
external threats.
even when workers get
organized, even once the overcome the constituent, internal
obstacles, their ability to win concessions is constrained by the
logic of accumulation—the context set by captialist competition.
the central conclusion
is that its not only economic outcomes that are governed by the logic
of accumulation, but also political outcomes.
this is why Marx spends
thirty years on DK.
first limit:
profitability—capitalism has in-built, system-wide
mechanisms which repel improvement of working-class life. if wages
rise, rate of investment declines, which means employment generation
slows down, the reserve army of labour rises, and wages are brought
down. this is the constraint of full employment. in contemporary
capitalism, bringing the State in, there exist institutions that
guarantee a baseline level of unemployment—the Fed's job is this,
basically ('profit-squeeze' theory of crisis would fit here).
this is a limit on the
system as a whole; wages as a whole, and profits as a whole.
but capital doesn't
exist as homogenous units that are identical. the level of
heterogeneity is important.
there are firms that
are very capital-intensive, some with better techniques, etc.
workers, when they
engage in bargaining, confront capitalists with different degrees of
productivity and capital intensity—which will mean that they will
incur different costs, when they concede to workers.
now, there are three
limits
(1) 'costs of
obstruction'--as soon as employees take up demands, employers
have to decide whether it is worth it to heed the immediate impulse
to repress their demands. where the costs of obstruction are
sufficiently high, the capitalist will not say 'no,' but will relent.
workers have to impose
costs sufficient to bring the employer to the table.
now, it will depend on
two things
(2) do you work for the
regulating capital?
reguating capitals are
those plants operating with the most widely available, more-or-less
widely available techniques. we're not talking about those plants
with unique, and impossible to replicate techniques.
otherwise, workers are
employed mainly in subdominant capitals.
the limits to wage
demands are greater in subdominant capitals than in regulating
capitals. an employer's ability to stay in business will depend on
his ability to re-adjust to these costs. regulating capitals have a
greater ability to recoup the losses that come from wage increases.
either they'll raise prices, or, more likely, some will leave the
sector, inducing higher prices through reduced supply.
after regulating
capitals have raised wages, subdominant capitals can be
organized—this is because they run the risk of going out of
business, if they raise prices before regulating capitals. but if
they do it after those have been successfully organized, workers have
a better shot.
(3) the capital
intensity of your sector
when wage costs are
high as a portion of total costs, wage increases are very difficult
for capital to accommodate.
in the history of the
US, this theoretical framework has purchase. it's at least part of
the reason that organizing in the South was less effective than
organizing in the North—it's not just racism, nor is it mainly
racism.
labour unions targeted
the 'price-leaders' in auto, rubber, etc. there was an understanding
that if we can organize these firms, the rest will follow. Weinberg,
research director at UAW, said (1) success at better firms is
important; (2) less efficient firms shouldn't be rewarded for being
less efficient by being allowed to avoid unions—in essence, trying
to replicate Sweden's efforts (though, w/o active labour market
policy, you're fucked).
it's as the crisis sets
in, and US industries cease to be regulating capitals on a global
level, they become less accommodating to wage increases—this, at
the same time that the labour movement calcifies into the
bureaucratic monolith with which we're familiar. hence, concession
after concession after concession is the story of the 1970s and
1980s.
- - -
difficulty is that
business unionism breeds in the context of declining industries
- - -
(1) getting rid of
labour-intensive jobs?
No comments:
Post a Comment