the agrarian question
development attends to social
formations with a large peasantry—so the 'agrarian question' is
essential to the problems of this course, naturally.
one and a half debates on the peasantry
that have really mattered
the first generation – from the first
decade of the 20th century to the middle of the 20th
century. trying to deal with the question of what would happen to the
peasantry as capiatalism spread. one answer was given by England—by
the time that this debate was happening, England was far and away an
urban country.
so people trying to understand the fate
of the peasantry, looking at England, would expect more or less
steady extinction. yet what they found, looking at continental Europe
and elsewhere, was different – much slower extinction, if any
(1) economic: what explains the
ability of the peasantry to persist, in the face of competition?
(2) political: what should
socialists do? Sdem parties rooted in the working-class were
concerned about what to do, when the bulk of the population was not
w-class. peasants demanding strengthening of individual property,
while w-class wanted socialization.
one easy answer was that history will
solve this for us. if we wait long enough, the peasantry will
disappear. the difficulty, though, again was that this wasn't
happening fast enough.
what will happen to the peasantry? if
they're not disappearing, why?
this was Kautsky's question.
when Kautsky started this book, he had
wanted to show that the peasantry was doomed to extinction. but what
he found was that there are actually mechanisms in place that allow
the peasantry to exist, however precariously.
the sources of persistence are of two
basic kinds: (1) peasants, when faced with more competitive
producers, have one advantage—they aren't motivated to produce at
the going rate of profit. for peasants the object of production is
survival. they'll accept returns on their labour that are far beneath
average – peasants will exploit themselves as is necessary.
capitalists, however, will only produce at an average or
above-average rate of return; they will withdraw at profits lower
than this; (2) insofar as peasants are able to hold on to their plots
of land, they end up being quite functional – (a) for employers in
rural areas, the persistence of the peasantry promises cheap labour
(costs of reproduction lowered by tiny plots of land); (b) insofar as
they're willing to exploit themselves, they lower the cost of food,
benefiting urban employers.
Kautsky and Lenin both recognized that
the entrance of capital doesn't result in them following the same
path that England did. capitalism can hold in place and accentuate
the non-transformation of social relations in agriculture:
agribusiness living in harmony with smallholders/small peasants.
the net result of this is not an
equilibrium, even-based economic development; but accentuated
unevenness.
this then brings up the next question.
what do you do about this?
the traditional answer has been land
reform. takes care of underemployment, produces income for peasants,
and perhaps produces more efficiency (compared to larger
landholdings). this last point is dubious (and the others depend on
the nature of the land reform, no doubt).
let's talk about the inverse
relationship of farm size-productivity.
Lenin versus 'populists' is rehashed,
here. Lenin's response was land vs. labour productivity. and the
basic point is the same, here.
in other words, giving land to peasants
is fine for urban elites, of course. but it's terrible for peasants,
welfare-wise.
exceedingly difficult to make judgments
of relative efficiency of investments. when you do measure them, the
relationship is a tenuous one.
- - -
not that it's not capitalism, but that
it's a very backward form of agrarian capitalism.
industrial transitions of late
developers are very different, but agrarian transitions are even more
different. these 'odd' forms generate endogenous obstacles, political
and economic.
an end-run around the problem of the
agrarian question through State-based cooperatives, etc.
GR allowed them to boost agricultural
productivity without changing property structures.
Kautsky writing in the context of the
influx of cheap grain, destroying peasantry; since the 1970s and
liberalization, we're living in a parallel phase of rapid
agricultural transition.
Patnaik's proposal that the internal
market be treated as the 'export market,' which presupposes that you
boost internal demand through boosting peasant incomes.
- - - -
in sum: Late developers find
themselves in a situation where the market isn't helping: agrarian
underdevelopment as capital comes in, and foreign endowments lock you
into cumulative disadvantages. This is where the State is supposed to
come in.
No comments:
Post a Comment