today rounds out solid discussion.
after today a lot is educated guesses (because that's where the
literature is)
where there is not educated guesses is
a descriptive account of what neoliberalism meant
but we don't have the same set of
analytical insights
underlying causes of implosion of the
State-led model.
we now need to revisit the issue of the
debt crisis, to discuss this in the terms developed in Vivek's book
as Rodrik argues, ISI interregnum
(1950-1980) was actually a 'world-historic success' (high relative to
normal growth rates in capitalism in first half of 20th
century, and high relative to what followed)
at the same time, ISI was a 'ticking
time bomb'. it had certain internal weaknesses (distinct from what
neoliberals thought, but still exist). these are political and
economic in nature.
economically, ISI could be of
discipliary and non-disciplinary nature. in E. Asia, you had the
former. in LA and Sasia you had the latter. this generated two
problems, which were self-reinforcing: (1) in the absence of
discipline, ISI became a gigantic subsidization scheme. meaning it
was an ever-expanding drain on the public exchequer. for this to be
sustainable, it had to be complemented by steady increases in
productivity, expanding the tax base, etc. this didn't happen. the
demands on the State outpaced the gains from subsidization. there
was, therefore, an ever-tightening fiscal crisis on the State; (2)
external debt problem, as well. because the developmental State was
not able to transform the external basket that they sold to the
world. they didn't quite move up the value-chain, in manufacturing.
because these countries were locked into buying capital goods, costs
outpaced gains. this was already evident by the 60s; this is why
Prebisch is arguing that the only way the development model would
survive is if it went whole hog on exports (and, unlike what's
stressed in dev. literature, country after country attempted
to export; only a few succeeded). firms uniformly opposed because it
was not something they could rationally accept to succeed
as a result of this, developing
countries are desperate for cheap loans. from 69-79, you get a longer
lease on life for ISI because of the very easy conditions on the
capital market. by '82, the chickens come home to roost.
in '79 you get the Volcker shock, which
means that loan payments being made by LDCs tripled or quadrupled.
every one of them comes into serious crisis, etc.
the underpinning of this is the
inability of the State to adequately transform the economy, in order
to get sufficient revenue from their economy. SK and Taiwan were
fine, even though they had large amounts of debt. but their revenues
were in good shape, fiscal and export.
the weakness of State-led development,
then, was a weakness of one kind of State intervention.
politically, when
capitalists changed their preferences away from ISI towards
neoliberalism, labour was so enfeebled that it was unable to gather
the power to do anything about it. in India, for example, labour was
demobilized; elsewhere, it was hemmed in by a maze of corporatist
arrangements that made its organizational power moot to what it could
give its constituents. official labour movements could do very little
to avert it. the only way they could resist was by cutting further
deals with political elites, etc.
in Korea, the
dismantling of the developmental State occurs prior to the crisis of
1997, in the early 90s. the chaebols start to see the discipline as
an encumbrance that they can cast off without threat to their
profits.
- cheap capital roots in petro-dollars?
- capitalists changing their preferences towards liberalization?
- - -
the smallness of size of mkt was not an
inducement to SK firms to hazard export markets. Jamaica, Syria, etc.
all stuck with ISI.
in Sweden, capitalists agree to keep
labour in the coalition b/c there's not much planning, and no real
public sector.
as early as late 19th
century, Sweden embarks on a high-technology export-based strategy.
in the 1930s/40s it has a highly developed industrial sector already,
despite having 30-40% agrarian strategy and being a 'developmental
case.'
at the end of the day, you're dancing
to capitalists' tune, and are always on a 'knife-edge'
late development vs. late-late
development is important to understanding Sweden in the late
nineteenth century. the latter face extraordinary pressures,
remember, that the former simply don't face—they're oligarchies,
etc.
capitalists never stop pushing for
subsidies. in neoliberalism, they want regulations/impositions to be
taken away, but not lose State assistance. behind the scenes
capitalists are still lobbying States for assistance, etc. you have
the luxury of a public posture of laissez faire, but the reality of
getting significant structural assistance. they want done away,
though, with obligations to labour, and obligations to invest
according to plan requirements.
enabling condition for shift to
neoliberalism will have to be stratified, but also global. you can't
simply say that 'everywhere' you have a shift in the balance of
forces. there's an underlying structural cause, which is the shift in
the 1960s, through the 70s, early 80s, in the US. of course,
independent of these changes, given the enfeeblement of the labour
movement, it's likely to develop into something like neoliberalism.
but the reason the US is important is because of the extraordinary
simultaneity you see in the transitions to neoliberalism.
inflation in ISI—really only a
problem in LA, wasn't as much of a problem in other parts of the
world.
increased confidence for lenders owing
to the fact that this is sovereign debt, not private debt.
governments are good for it.
No comments:
Post a Comment